-
(单词翻译:双击或拖选)
Should digital monopolies be broken up?
European moves against Google are about protecting companies, not consumers
ALTHOUGH no company is mentioned by name, it is very clear which American internet giant the European Parliament has in mind in a resolution that has been doing the rounds in the run-up to a vote on November 27th. One draft calls for “unbundling search engines from other commercial services” to ensure a level playing field for European companies and consumers. This is the latest and most dramatic outbreak of Googlephobia in Europe.
Europe's former competition commissioner1, Joaquín Almunia, brokered2 a series of settlements this year requiring Google to give more prominence3 to rivals' shopping and map services alongside its own in search results. But MEPs want his successor, Margrethe Vestager, to take a firmer line. Hence the calls to dismember the company.
The parliament does not actually have the power to carry out this threat. But it touches on a question that has been raised by politicians from Washington to Seoul and brings together all sorts of issues from privacy to industrial policy. How worrying is the dominance of the internet by Google and a handful of other firms?
Who's afraid of the big bad search engine?
Google (whose executive chairman, Eric Schmidt, is a member of the board of The Economist's parent company) has 68% of the market of web searches in America and more than 90% in many European countries. Like Facebook, Amazon and other tech giants, it benefits from the network effects whereby the popularity of a service attracts more users and thus becomes self-perpetuating. It collects more data than any other company and is better at mining those data for insights. Once people start using Google's search (and its e-mail, maps and digital storage), they rarely move on. Small advertisers find switching to another platform too burdensome to bother.
Google is clearly dominant4, then; but whether it abuses that dominance is another matter. It stands accused of favouring its own services in search results, making it hard for advertisers to manage campaigns across several online platforms, and presenting answers on some search pages directly rather than referring users to other websites. But its behaviour is not in the same class as Microsoft's systematic5 campaign against the Netscape browser6 in the late 1990s: there are no e-mails talking about “cutting off” competitors' “air supply”. What's more, some of the features that hurt Google's competitors benefit its consumers. Giving people flight details, dictionary definitions or a map right away saves them time. And while advertisers often pay hefty rates for clicks, users get Google's service for nothing—rather as plumbers7 and florists8 fork out to be listed in Yellow Pages which are given to readers gratis9, and nightclubs charge men steep entry prices but let women in free.
There are also good reasons why governments should regulate internet monopolies less energetically than offline ones. First, barriers to entry are lower in the digital realm. It has never been easier to launch a new online product or service: consider the rapid rise of Instagram, WhatsApp or Slack. Building a rival infrastructure10 to a physical incumbent11 is far more expensive (just ask telecoms operators or energy firms), and as a result there is much less competition (and more need for regulation) in the real world. True, big firms can always buy upstart rivals (as Facebook did with Instagram and WhatsApp, and Google did with Waze, Apture and many more). But such acquisitions then encourage the formation of even more start-ups, creating even more competition for incumbents12.
Second, although switching from Google and other online giants is not costless, their products do not lock customers in as Windows, Microsoft's operating system, did. And although network effects may persist for a while, they do not confer a lasting13 advantage: consider the decline of MySpace, or more recently of Orkut, Google's once-dominant social network in Brazil, both eclipsed by Facebook—itself threatened by a wave of messaging apps.
Finally, the lesson of recent decades is that technology monopolists (think of IBM in mainframes or Microsoft in PC operating systems) may be dominant for a while, but they are eventually toppled when they fail to move with the times, or when new technologies expand the market in unexpected ways, exposing them to new rivals. Facebook is eating into Google's advertising14 revenue. Despite the success of Android, Google's mobile platform, the rise of smartphones may undermine Google: users now spend more time on apps than on the web, and Google is gradually losing control of Android as other firms build their own mobile ecosystems15 on top of its open-source underpinnings. So far, no company has remained information technology's top dog from one cycle to the next. Sometimes former monopolies end up with a lucrative16 franchise17 in a legacy18 area, as Microsoft and IBM have. But the kingdoms they rule turn out to be only part of a much larger map.
Looking after their own
The European Parliament's Googlephobia looks a mask for two concerns, one worthier19 than the other. The lamentable20 one, which American politicians pointed21 out this week, is a desire to protect European companies. Among the loudest voices lobbying against Google are Axel Springer and Hubert Burda Media, two German media giants. Instead of attacking successful American companies, Europe's leaders should ask themselves why their continent has not produced a Google or a Facebook. Opening up the EU's digital services market would do more to create one than protecting local incumbents.
The good reason for worrying about the internet giants is privacy. It is right to limit the ability of Google and Facebook to use personal data: their services should, for instance, come with default settings guarding privacy, so companies gathering22 personal information have to ask consumers to opt23 in. Europe's politicians have shown more interest in this than American ones. But to address these concerns, they should regulate companies' behaviour, not their market power. Some clearer thinking by European politicians would benefit the continent's citizens.
1 commissioner | |
n.(政府厅、局、处等部门)专员,长官,委员 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 brokered | |
adj.由权力经纪人安排(或控制)的v.做掮客(或中人等)( broker的过去式和过去分词 );作为权力经纪人进行谈判;以中间人等身份安排… | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 prominence | |
n.突出;显著;杰出;重要 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 dominant | |
adj.支配的,统治的;占优势的;显性的;n.主因,要素,主要的人(或物);显性基因 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 systematic | |
adj.有系统的,有计划的,有方法的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 browser | |
n.浏览者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 plumbers | |
n.管子工,水暖工( plumber的名词复数 );[美][口](防止泄密的)堵漏人员 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 florists | |
n.花商,花农,花卉研究者( florist的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 gratis | |
adj.免费的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 infrastructure | |
n.下部构造,下部组织,基础结构,基础设施 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 incumbent | |
adj.成为责任的,有义务的;现任的,在职的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 incumbents | |
教区牧师( incumbent的名词复数 ); 教会中的任职者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 lasting | |
adj.永久的,永恒的;vbl.持续,维持 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 advertising | |
n.广告业;广告活动 a.广告的;广告业务的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 ecosystems | |
n.生态系统( ecosystem的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 lucrative | |
adj.赚钱的,可获利的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 franchise | |
n.特许,特权,专营权,特许权 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 legacy | |
n.遗产,遗赠;先人(或过去)留下的东西 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 worthier | |
应得某事物( worthy的比较级 ); 值得做某事; 可尊敬的; 有(某人或事物)的典型特征 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 lamentable | |
adj.令人惋惜的,悔恨的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 pointed | |
adj.尖的,直截了当的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 gathering | |
n.集会,聚会,聚集 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 opt | |
vi.选择,决定做某事 | |
参考例句: |
|
|